On the 2nd of May 2010 the
"troika" agreed to a 110 billion bailout package for Greece, in what the European leaders hoped would draw a
line in the sand in the sovereign debt crisis that would soon became known as the Eurozone crisis. But contrary to their hopes, this was just the
beginning of a wave that would also engulf Ireland and Portugal, threaten Spain
and Italy; and with it the very existence of the Euro. The main causes
of the market turmoil, according to the great majority of experts, were the
"unsustainable" debt burdens and deficits. Yet, when one compares the
debt burdens for the affected countries at the beginning of the Eurozone crisis
to those this countries had back in 1995/96, one can easily see that 2008’s debt
burdens were not significantly out of line with those in 1995/1996, and in some
cases this were even lower, such is the case of Italy, but back then there was
no talk of default; nor did these countries have any problems financing
themselves.
Italy's debt burden,
measured by debt-to-GDP, rose from 90% to reach a peak of 121% in 1995,
following the recession of the early 90's, but it went down steadily since and
at the beginning of the Great Recession, in 2008, it stood at 106%
"only". With the onset of the recession the trend was inverted and
the debt burden started to rise again, but in 2011, at 120%, this was still
below the 1996 value. On the other hand,
the deficits, measured as deficit-to-GDP, have remained below the 5% mark which
is a stark contrast with the 10% or more during the early 90's recession.
In addition, while Italy's
ten-year bond yields rose to their highest euro-area level after 2011, they
remain well below the yields of 10% or more paid in the early 90's
recession. In 1995, with a debt burden
of 121%, a deficit of 7% and paying yields of 12%, Italy had no problems
financing itself, but in 2011 with a debt of 121%, a deficit of 3% and yields
of 5%, Italy's debts costs were
now considered unsustainable and markets started to see it as default risk, which led governments to
impose austerity measures.
It’s reasonable to conclude
that for these countries something fundamental has changed in relation to their
recent past; somehow they are now subject to market forces they had never
experienced before. Forces that can ultimately push theme to default, as in the
case of Greece, or to adopt austerity measures in the middle of a recession
with high levels of unemployment. All of a sudden the bond vigilantes became more
important than the voters.
So the question is what
changed? Why are these countries subject
to market discipline like they have never experienced before? Why are they
having difficulties financing their debts when this was not a problem
before? Why are their debts and deficits
now considered unsustainable while in the 90's, similar or worst levels, where
not considered a serious problem? Why are these countries adopting austerity
measures in the middle of a recession?
In addition, one has to wonder if the Maastricht limits on debt and
deficits are so important, why were Italy and Greece ever allowed to join the
Euro with debts well over the 60%? Put
simply, what changed was the Euro and the Maastricht limits never really
mattered. To understand why, however, we must understand what changed with the introduction of the Euro.
Although the term
Eurosceptic has been used to cobble together a diverse group of people and
points of views, mostly non-economics related, there are at least two discernable
groups of economists that were sceptical about the Euro experience on economic
grounds. The mainstream view, that thought of the euro in terms
of the theory of the “optimum currency area” , theory which was itself
the basis of the monetary union, concluded within the framework that the costs
could outweighed the benefits and as such were against the euro from the
beginning; On the other hand, despite
arriving at the same conclusion, a fringe group of economists , the neo-Chartalists, takes a competitive
approach to money as a starting point. While the implicit theory behind the
Optimum Currency Area is the Metallits approach to Money that defends that
Money was invented to facilitate trade, to the neo-Chartalists money is a
creature of the state, and this mean not only that the state determines what is
money but also that it drives its acceptance by demanding that taxes are paid
in the currency of its choice. (For a presentation of the competitive approach
and a critic to the optimum currency areas theory see Charles Goodhart ).
Even though, many others
neo-chartalists and MMT's have long warned to the consequences of the faulty
construction of the Euro, I want here to highlight in particular an article by
the late Wynne Godley published in 1992
under the tittle Maastricht and All That, and a paper by Randall
Wray with the title of Is Euroland the Next
Argentina from 2001, both scholars of the Levy Institute, where several scholars
issued warnings well in advance of the Euro area sovereign debt crisis. While Wynne’s article
explains not only the flawed views that governed the constitution of the
monetary union but also the consequences of not having a Central (Federal)
government, the paper by Randall Wray, taking as a starting point the Argentina
experiment with the dollarization and establishing some parallels with the Euro
experiment, makes not only some insightful predictions to what would later
became the Eurozone crisis but also possible solutions if the crisis came to
materialize.
Monetary sovereign nations vs non sovereign states
Some aspects of the theory might be controversial and at times seem counterintuitive but the main idea can be resumed in Charles Goodhart corollary: "One government, one money" or one currency, one nation" to which we all can relate easily, once this is the model for most countries, or at least it was until the introduction of the Euro, with the exception of some small states like Monaco, San Marino and the like. What derives naturally from the on-to-one correspondence between countries and currencies is the definition of monetary sovereignty, which can be understood as the" exclusive" and "unlimited" power of the government to issue its own money.
A Monetarily Sovereign government has the exclusively unlimited power to create its sovereign currency. This exclusive power, nowadays delegated in the central bank, means that it has a monopoly of currency issuance, as such no other government or entity can issue the sovereign currency. The unlimited part refers to the fact that it can create as much of it as it desires. This does not mean that it should, as it might have undesired effects, most important of all inflation, but only that there are no financial limits to its issuing power. There might be some legal restrictions, as the debt ceiling in the US or the budgetary process is most of the countries, but this are self-imposed rather than built-in restrictions. Government creates money by paying its bills and retires it by taxing. Therefore, a monetary sovereign state does not have to tax or borrow money prior to spending it.
A Monetarily Sovereign government has the exclusively unlimited power to create its sovereign currency. This exclusive power, nowadays delegated in the central bank, means that it has a monopoly of currency issuance, as such no other government or entity can issue the sovereign currency. The unlimited part refers to the fact that it can create as much of it as it desires. This does not mean that it should, as it might have undesired effects, most important of all inflation, but only that there are no financial limits to its issuing power. There might be some legal restrictions, as the debt ceiling in the US or the budgetary process is most of the countries, but this are self-imposed rather than built-in restrictions. Government creates money by paying its bills and retires it by taxing. Therefore, a monetary sovereign state does not have to tax or borrow money prior to spending it.
On the other hand, non-monetary
sovereign states don't possess this exclusive and unlimited power to create the
currency they use and so they have the status of a local authorities. These are
users of the currency rather than issuers and as such they must borrow or
tax before they can spend it. Us states and Swiss Cantons are a good example of non-monetary
sovereign states.
The degree of monetary
sovereignty depends as well on the exchange-rate regime. When a country pegs it currency to a foreign
currency or to a commodity like gold, it limits its power to create money as it
must manage its holding of reserves of the foreign currency or commodity, if
the promise is to be credible, otherwise, it might have to break its promise to
convert at a fixed rate, as eventually always happens. As a result, a second
important element of the monetary sovereignty is a flexible exchange-rate. A flexible exchange rate is not only
important to guarantee currency independency but also a condition to have
fiscal independence.
Money financed deficit
"While we commonly think of a government needing to first receive tax revenue, and then spending that revenue, this sequence is quite obviously not necessary for any sovereign government." (Randall Wray)
Monetary sovereign countries can spend before they tax, this is actually necessary if one takes the view the state has a monopoly of money creation, as it must spend (lend) the money into creation before it can tax (borrow) it, which contradicts the current dogma that the government always needs to tax or borrow first before it can spent. A sovereign government it's not revenue constrained. This is easy to see if one thinks that the Government (Treasury) has a printing press and prints money as it needs to buy goods or services. However, if this was the case in the past, the introduction of the (1) Central Bank and (2) governments debt securities has blurred the picture. Picture that was already distorted by the fact that paper money and coins represent a small amount of the monetary base, which in addition to coins and paper money (both as bank vault cash and as currency circulating in the public), includes commercial banks' reserves with the central bank. This highly liquid government created money is also called high powered money (HPM). Thus, a more accurate version of the "printing money" is one that incorporates not only new issuance of paper currency but mainly the crediting of reserve accounts at the central bank as explained by Randall Wray:
"The sovereign government
spends (buys goods, services, or assets, or makes transfer payments) by issuing
a Treasury check, or, increasingly, by simply crediting a private bank deposit. In either case, however,
credit balances (HPM) are created when the Fed credits the reserve account of
the receiving bank. Exactly analogously, when the government receives tax
payments, it reduces the reserve balance of a member bank (and, hence the
quantity of HPM). Simultaneously, the taxpayer’s bank deposit is debited, and
her bank’s reserves at the Fed are reduced. While we commonly think of a
government needing to first receive tax revenue, and then spending that
revenue, this sequence is quite obviously not necessary for any sovereign
government. If a government spends by crediting a bank account (issuing its
own IOU--HPM) and taxes by debiting a bank account (and eliminating its IOU--
HPM), then it is not as a matter of logic “spending” tax revenue. In other
words, with a floating exchange rate and a domestic currency, the sovereign
government’s ability to make payments is not revenue-constrained."
This institutional
arrangement, with the central bank acting as both the banker's bank and the
government's bank, opens a range of options for coordination between the
Treasury and the Central Bank that would not be available if the Treasury had a
bank account at any private bank. It not only allows that one part of the
government (Central Bank) to "finance" other part of the government
(Treasury) but also that both can coordinate when setting interest rates. In other words, the central bank can help the
government with the implementation of its fiscal policy and government can
assist with monetary policy:
"The Federal
Reserve influences the economy through the market for balances that depository
institutions maintain in their accounts at Federal Reserve banks. Banks keep
reserves at Federal Reserve banks to meet reserve requirements and to clear
financial transactions." ( New York Fed)
The operations between
treasury and Central Bank can take the form of overdrafts and cash advancements
on the Treasury account at the Central Bank -"printing money"- and
the purchase of government debt securities in the primary market or secondary
market. Whether the government
"prints money" or the government issues securities that are latter
purchased by the central bank has the same end result as demonstrated by Stephanie Kelton:
"There is virtually no
macroeconomically significant difference between the Fed providing the Treasury
with an overdraft versus the Fed owning the short-term debt of the Treasury—the
Fed will return any interest it receives on the T-bill or the overdraft to the
Treasury along with the rest of its profits."
While in the past two
decades many countries have been passing
legislation with a view to restricting this operations between the Treasury and
the Central Bank, as a recent paper by the
IMF on central bank regulation around the world highlights, MMT argues that this are
self- imposed constrains and can be easily surpassed by the Treasury and
central bank when needed, as quantitative easing has shown. However, this regulation has had the effect of reinforcing the belief that Treasury must tax or borrow
before it spends as in effect, due to this self-imposed restrictions, the Treasury
must maintain a positive balance in its account at the central bank, which it
can do only by receiving tax balances or by issuing debt securities in the open
market. Even if due to current legislative restrictions the Treasury is forced
to keep a positive balance on its account at the central bank that should not
distract from the fact that it all starts with the government spending first,
as Frank N. Newman, former
Deputy Secretary of the U.S. Treasury (1994-1995), explained ( by Stephanie
Kelton):
"I recall from my time at the Treasury Department that the assumption was always that there was money in the fed account to start with. Nobody seemed to know where it came from originally or when; perhaps it was established in biblical times. But as a matter of practice, if the treasury wanted to disburse $20bn a given day, it started with at least that much in its fed account. Then later would issue new treasuries and rebuild its account at the fed. (I do not recall ever using an overdraft.)
In my view, this is still
consistent with the MMT perspective that you mentioned, and in my own book the
explanation starts the cycle with government spending, thus adding to the money
supply, and then issuing treasuries for roughly equivalent amount, thus
restoring the money supply and the Treasury’s Fed account to the levels they
were prior to that round of spending. Every cycle is: spend first, then issue
treasuries to replenish the fed account. The fact that Treasury started the
period with some legacy funds in its Fed account is not really relevant to
understanding the current flow of funds in any year."
In practise, however, this is a bit more complicated but the essence is maintained:
"In practice, Treasury varies its issuance not only to match outlays, but also to deal with seasonal factors, and to avoid wide swings in new-issue sizes; so at one point of a year, treasury might actually issue some extra securities because the next month was expected to have low tax revenues, or might not fully replenish recent spending because the next month was expected to have high tax revenues. That seasonal process doesn't really affect the overall flow of funds over a year. The substance of the cycle is still: spend then replenish. Debating that would seem highly philosophical, and would miss the practical aspects of the flows."
If the government spending
always comes first why does the government need to issue government debt
securities? This brings us to one of the central point of the MMT which is the
fact that government debt securities don't serve the purpose of
"financing" a sovereign government but are instead an instrument to
implement monetary policy:
"Transactions in
the federal funds market allow depository institutions with reserve balances in
excess of reserve requirements to sell reserves to institutions with reserve
deficiencies at an interest rate known as the fed funds rate. The FOMC sets
the target for the fed funds rate at a level it believes will foster
financial and monetary conditions consistent with achieving its monetary policy
objectives and adjusts that target in line with evolving economic developments."
( New York Fed)
While Treasury spending
leads to monetary creation (bank reserve balances at the central bank),
taxation has the opposite effect as it involves monetary destruction.
Therefore, if the treasury spends more then what it takes in taxes (i.e. runs a
deficit), it creates net excess
reserves in the interbank market -in excess of what banks want or are required
to hold- as such putting downward pressure in the interbank rate (rate at
which banks lend reserves to each
other), all the way to zero. Unless that's the target rate of the Central Bank,
which in normal times rarely is, it must drain the excess reserves to achieve
the desired rate. Treasury surpluses have just the opposite effect, they drain
reserves and in this situation the Central Bank must supply reserves otherwise
rates will rise above the target rate. The Central Bank supplies and drains
reserves through its open market operations:
"The Fed uses three
tools to implement monetary policy, the most important being open market
operations. These “domestic operations” are conducted for the System only by
the New York Fed under direction of the FOMC. Through open market
operations, the Fed buys or sells U.S. Treasury securities in the secondary market
to produce a desired level of bank reserves. These securities are held in
the System’s portfolio, which is known as the System Open Market Account or
“SOMA.”"( New York Fed)
This Open Market Operations
consist mostly on the sell and purchase of government debt securities by the
Central Bank. When the Central Bank wants to drain the excess reserve created
by deficits, it sells government debt securities to the banks until demand and
supply match at the target rate. On the contrary, when it wants to supply
liquidity, it buys the government securities from the banks until they have
their desired holdings of reserves at the target rate. As the holdings of
government securities for the Open Market Operations by the Central Bank are
limited, this opens the door for further cooperation with the Treasury, so the later can provide enough debt securities to allow effective rate targeting. This idea
was resumed in Randall Wray:
"Note that the sale of
its own treasuries by a sovereign government is not best thought of as a
borrowing operation, even though it is frequently described as such. Rather,
the purpose of such sales (even if policy- makers do not realize this) is to
drain any excess reserves created by deficit spending. If the bond sales were
not undertaken to drain excess reserves, the overnight rate would fall.
Operationally, the Treasury and the Central Bank work together to ensure that
the overnight interest rate target (set by monetary policy) is hit. They do
this through security sales or purchases to drain or add reserves as necessary
to allow the monetary authorities to hit rate targets."
Interest rate on government debt securities
But what drives banks
preference to hold governments securities instead of reserve balances at the
Central Bank? The main reason it's interest payment: reserve balances at the Central
Bank do not pay interest, at least they did not until
the recent financial crises, while government debt securities do pay. So, for banks the choice it’s
always between non-interest paying reserve balances at the Central Bank or
interest bearing government securities. Profit seeking banks, with excess
reserves, will want to hold any combination that maximizes their profit. Which
simple means that besides any reserves they are required or want to hold they
will want all the government securities they can get their hands on. This has
important implications, namely that interest rate paid on government securities
of a sovereign government are not subjected to market forces as explained by
Randall Wary:
"The final point to
be made regarding such operations by a sovereign government is that the
interest rate paid on treasury securities is not subject to normal “market
forces”. The sovereign government only sells securities in order to drain
excess reserves to hit its interest rate target. It could always choose to
simply leave excess reserves in the banking system, in which case the overnight
rate would fall toward zero. When the overnight rate is zero, the Treasury can
always offer to sell securities that pay a few basis points above zero and will
find willing buyers because such securities offer a better return than the
alternative (zero). This drives home the point that a sovereign government
with a floating currency can issue securities at any rate it desires—normally a
few basis points above the overnight interest rate target it has set. There
may well be economic or political reasons for keeping the overnight rate above
zero (which means the interest rate paid on securities will also be above zero) But it is simply false
reasoning that leads to the belief that the size of a sovereign government
deficit affects the interest rate paid on securities."
Japan is a case in point:
since the 90's its budget deficit and debt increased steadily until 2005 but, contrary
to conventional wisdom, this was accompanied by a fall in Government bond
yields. In actual fact, government bond yields actually increased slightly when
a reduction of the deficit was initiated in 2005. However, since the onset of
the great recession, the budget deficit has reversed course and started to increase again and now stands above
10% of GDP, with little sign it will abate anytime soon. Once again, contrary
to the mainstream view, bond yields have fallen further. The situation was made
even worse with the earthquake in 2011, which prompt many to predict that the
day of reckoning was around the corner:
We are now in 2015 and that
day has not yet arrived. On the contrary, Japan debt burden has increased and
the IMF estimates that at the end 2014 it
will be 242% GDP, yet there's no sign of the day of reckoning is closer than in
2011 as bond yields are getting ever
close to Zero despite the proposed record budget for 2014.
Demand for government debt securities
Another important point to be made from the graph above is that against all predictions there is no shortage of demand for Japan's debt securities as its outstanding debt just keeps on increasing. In fact, as Frank N. Newman, former Deputy Secretary of the U.S. Treasury (1994-1995), explains in the same post by Stephanie Kelton, there's never shortage of demand for sovereign government debt securities:
"In any case, the
treasury can always raise money by issuing securities. The bond vigilantes
really have it backwards. There is always more demand for treasuries than can
be allocated from a limited supply of new issues in each auction; the winners
in the auctions get to place their funds in the safest most liquid form of
instrument there is for US dollars; the losers are stuck keeping some of their
funds in banks, with bank risk. (I even try to avoid using the expression
“borrow” when the treasury issues securities; the treasury is providing an
opportunity for investors to move funds from risky banks to safe and liquid treasuries.)"
The reason why there's
always demand for debt securities of a sovereign government that issues its
debt in its own currency is that it produces the most safe and liquid of all
the securities in that sovereign currency as explained by the Federal
Reserve Bank of ST. Louis:
"As the sole
manufacturer of dollars, whose debt is denominated in dollars, the U.S.
government can never become insolvent, i.e., unable to pay its bills. In this
sense, the government is not dependent on credit markets to remain operational.
Moreover, there will always be a market for U.S. government debt at home
because the U.S. government has the only means of creating risk-free
dollar-denominated assets (by virtue of never facing insolvency and paying
interest rates over the inflation rate, e.g., TIPS—Treasury Inflation-Protected
Securities)."
This can easily be illustrated with an example that so many times has caused confusion because this is not understood. Contrary to Japan, where
only 6% of outstanding bonds are held by non-residents, in the US non-residents
hold more than 30% of outstanding Treasury securities, being China and Japan the
biggest foreign holders, although only Chinese holdings are singled out as being a national
threat. As China has been running trade surpluses with the US (US trade deficits)
for years the accumulation of dollars or dollar denominated assets is just a
natural consequence of that trade pattern.
As the Chinese exporters must be paid in renminbi (yuan), US importers
must exchange their dollars for renminbis at the People's Bank of China (PBC),
the issuer of renminbis. The transaction increases People's Bank of China (PBC)
dollar reserves, that must be held in a bank account in a US bank (ignoring the
Eurodollar market), unless it prefers to hold the dollar bills in its vaults,
which for sure is not the case. At the end of the day, the PBC has only a
couple of options: 1. Exchanges it for another currency (a bank balance in
another country); 2. Keep the balance in dollars at a US bank, or 3. Buy dollar
denominated assets (US Debt). Assuming it prefers to keep its balance in
dollars, the choice is between the most liquid, most safe (no default risk), interest
bearing asset in dollars-i.e. Treasuries- over less liquid, less safe (bank
account carry default risk) that bear little or no interest- bank balance. There's little doubt which one is preferable. That's the choice faced not only by foreign deposit
holders but also the decision that many other large surplus deposit holders
face every day, from Social Security and other government funds to insurance
companies, mutual funds, pension funds and the like. Not surprising all of them
are big holders of Treasury
Securities.
Non-Sovereign governments: deficit financing, interest rate and demand for debt securities
A non-Sovereign government,
however, does not have unlimited power to create its currency as such rather
than an issuer of the currency it is a user of the currency. Contrary to a
sovereign government, a non-sovereign government must obtain "money"
before spending it, which it can only do by taxing or borrowing. By drawing
cheques on a private bank account, not at the Central Bank, a
non-sovereign nation must ensure it has money on the account at all times otherwise
the cheque might bounce. When it spends, its accounts at the private bank are debited
and when it receives taxes its accounts are credited. Any shortfall of taxes in
relation to spending must be borrowed from a bank or by issuing debt
securities. Whichever the case, it will receive a deposit to spend. At the end
of the term, it must have collected enough money to repay the principal and
interest or be able to roll over the loan.
The issuance of debt by a non-sovereign government is truly a financing
operation in the terms we are used to think of it. First implication is that
interest rates for a non-sovereign are ultimately determined by market forces
as Randall notes:
"Since it is borrowing
dollars/euros, the rate it pays is determined by two factors. First there is
the base rate on dollars/euros set by the monetary policy of the US government
(the issuer of the dollar) or the ECB (issuer of the euro). On top of that is
the market’s assessment of the nonsovereign government’s credit worthiness.
A large number of factors may go into determining this assessment. The
important point, however, is that the nonsovereign government, as user (not
issuer) of a currency cannot exogenously set the interest rate. Rather, market
forces determine the interest rate at which it borrows."
If markets perceive the credit worthiness of a government is deteriorating it can increase rates and ultimately turn off the tap. This can be especially worrying during recessions when tax revenues fall and borrowing increases. In such a situation, market sentiment can change very quickly and the government might find it difficult to borrow, whether for new spending or to roll over debt, and be forced to cut spending or even default if costs of borrowing became too high. Therefore, the ability of a non-sovereign government to pay its bills is not unlimited once it depends not only on its powers to tax but as well on "perceived" default risk.